April 24, 2016
Let and be two strategies (formally defined later, take it to mean :choice of action” ) for player and let be the set of all possible strategy profiles for the other players. Then we say that:
strictly dominates if
i.e. if, for every joint set of actions the other player will take, the utility player gets by playing is strictly more than the utility gets when they play
very weakly dominates if
i.e. if, for every joint set of actions the other player will take, the utility player gets by playing is greater than or equal to more than the utility gets when they play
When a strategy dominates another strategy, you don’t need to think about what the other agents will do in order to decide that you would prefer to play instead of . If one strategy dominates all others, we say it is dominant. If this is the case, then is better than everything else (i.e. it is the best thing to do). If you have a dominant strategy, you don’t need to worry about what the other agents will do, you can always play the dominant strategy.
Claim: A strategy profile consisting of dominant strategies for every player must be a Nash equilibrium. This must be true because since all the strategies are dominant, no agent will want to change their strategy. Furthermore, an equilibrium in a strictly dominant strategy must be unique. If not, it is not strictly dominant.
Consider the following matrix:
Claim: Player 1 has a dominant strategy, which is playing . We can prove this using a case analysis:
Therefore, regardless to what Player 2 does, PLayer 1’s best response is to strictly choose . Therefore is a dominant strategy. The same case analysis applies to Player 2 (symmetric)